Saturday, November 10, 2012

A question for extreme signalling theorists

I think we all agree that signaling is an important part of the relationship between education and wages, and it's simply an important facet of human behavior to keep in mind. But some people think it's a lot more important than others and - much like voter irrationality in prior years - that share will increase significantly in the next couple years.

So maybe you guys can help me with something I was thinking about.

Some schools have tougher admission standards than others and if you can get in a tough school you try to because the reputation of that school is going to signal something good about you. Going through four years at a tough school shows that you can handle tough situations that are structured and perhaps that have a professional or white collar flavor to them.

But what I don't get is this: academic labor markets, or the market for professors, sorts in the same way. You have to have a PhD from an excellent school to get a job at an excellent school or a very good school. You have to have a PhD from a very good school to get a job at a very good school or a good school. If you get a PhD at a good school life will be harder for you than if you got a PhD at a very good school or an excellent school, and you should probably think of a variety of jobs aside from an academic job. (I am assuming here the traditional assumption that PhD programs are mostly about human capital investments and not signalling - although if you've ever tried to apply for a research grant without a PhD you know it's part signalling too).

This sorting makes sense on the students' end of things, but it doesn't make nearly as much sense (in an extreme sorting scenario) for the academic labor market end. You don't have to have an excellent academic pedigree to make undergrads work extremely hard. I'm not the most brilliant at math - not close. But I know more than enough to make life hell for undergraduates and separate the wheat from the chaff - which is what is allegedly done in the signalling model. A lot of economics departments don't even require that undergrad economics be taught with calculus. Simply making that leap is something anyone with a graduate degree from anywhere in the country could do in the curriculum. In other words, you don't need a top-tier PhD to perform the task of providing signals to employers about students. That's relatively easy. Even bad professors (who are usually bad because they're bad teachers and not because they don't know the material themselves) can rank student qualities pretty well (which is all the signalling model asks of them).

So what explains the high correlation between the toughness of a school for undergraduates and the caliber of the professors they hire? It makes no sense under the signalling model!

If you think of professors as doing two jobs - assigning students signals (i.e. - grades in a course) and research - you would actually expect the brilliant researchers to eschew schools that were known for rigorous assignment of signals. Teaching undergrads is a distraction from research. Let the professors with degrees from third or fourth tier universities challenge the undergrads at the really tough schools like Harvard or Princeton. Leave the professors with degrees from top tier schools to teach at the no-name college where they can get research done (or let them do it at independent research institutes with no signal-assignment obligation at all).

But this isn't what we see. We see the smartest professors teaching at the schools that are the toughest for undergraduates. We also see institutional arrangements that force them to teach and assign signals to undergraduates.

Why would this happen under a signalling model? Employers don't really need a top-tier PhD to separate the wheat from the chaff do they? It makes no sense with a signalling model.

It makes good sense if you think people go to a tough school to a large extent to get an excellent human capital investment. Signalling is obviously a part of the story, but you'd think the academic labor market would look very different if it were a big part of the story.

So what am I missing? How does the signalling model explain the fact that academic labor markets seem to sort in the same way that undergraduates do?

10 comments:

  1. One explanation, of course, is that top tier profs are required to teach top tier PhD students, and the undergrads are an afterthought.

    But that just kicks the can down the road. Why are tough undergrad programs so tightly correlated with tough PhD programs? Why put that extra challenge-and-rank-the-undergrads responsibility on top of the train-the-PhDs responsibility if not for the primacy of human capital?

    ReplyDelete
  2. "A lot of economics departments don't even require that undergrad economics be taught with calculus."

    ??? Really

    ReplyDelete
    Replies
    1. In my experience at my college, they only required an introductory statistics course for econometrics, though they're now changing that to a 200-level statistics course. I think it should be a requirement for students to have at least mastered Calculus I and Calculus II if they wish to have a Bachelor of Arts in Economics, and to go up to Differential Equations (and a 200 level course in statistics, preferably involving exploratory data analysis) if they wish to have a Bachelor of Science in Economics. But that's just my view.

      Delete
  3. You have to ask what is the signalling for. It is to obtain the best possible position. If universities were perfect signal discriminators, but then ignored those signals in awarding their positions, the signal would be useless to the would be signalers. Signaling must be useful to both the employer and the employee or it is of no use at all.

    ReplyDelete
    Replies
    1. Right, and there are lots of ways that professors signal in the academic job market. But generally even extreme signalling theorists hold that PhDs are for actual human capital development and impart actual productivity as an academic. Certainly these academics signal, but why the correlation with undergraduate quality. Presumably an institution teeming with undergraduates is going to distract from research if all those undergraduates have to be assigned signals five times every semester.

      If signalling were the real issue I'd think you'd see low-quality PhDs teaching undergraduates at all institutions, and high-quality PhDs getting jobs at pure research institutes where they only do research and train other PhDs. But that's not the case. You have top-tier PhDs spending a lot of their time teaching and assigning signals to undergraduates.

      If they aren't doing a lot of human capital development it seems to me it's a massive waste of human resources.

      If they are, it makes a lot more sense.

      Delete
    2. There isn't enough research money to go around. The bread and butter for academia is undergraduate teaching, the work side of the research fun side. It probably isn't even productive for people to spend full time in research since new ideas are not that common. Even teaching with the opportunity to do some research is more attractive to many than non academic work. Since there will always be more produced by high quality institutions than they can use, they must provide the rest with some opportunities to provide some value to that signal. So it seems the question is why higher quality institutions don't get out of undergraduate education entirely, and it is because that is where the money is, not solely in education but also in alumni. An institution that produced only academics would not be highly successful financially.

      Delete
  4. Not entirely sure how this fits into the discussion, but a friend of mine recently did his postgrad at Harvard. As part of his research stipend, he was assigned as TA to Mankiw's introductory economics course.

    He told me that "almost impossible to fail" at Harvard during the undergrad, because everything is so neatly laid out for the students. They are, according to him, almost spoon-fed the content and TAs in particular a tremendous work load i.t.o. preparing summary notes, etc. Of course, I'd imagine that the student body is comprised of extremely talented and hard-working individuals at the same time... but his impression is that most people could do reasonably well there.

    OTOH, this friend also took various classes at MIT... and his impressions there were almost completely the opposite. Students were left much to their own devices and had to spent much more time solving problems and sourcing material themselves.

    ReplyDelete
    Replies
    1. Blegh. Several typos in the above comment.

      *that it's
      *have a tremendous
      etc

      Delete
  5. Going to an excellent school allows you to affiliate with very impressive people, and the value of those affiliations come mostly through signaling.

    ReplyDelete

All anonymous comments will be deleted. Consistent pseudonyms are fine.